About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

15 Tax Mag. 83 (1937)
Who Pays the Taxes

handle is hein.journals/taxtm15 and id is 83 raw text is: L YLE OWEN
of Carnegie Institute of
Technology answers an
important question as to
Who Pays the
Taxes?
T HE rapidly mounting cost of government, with
its accompanying increase in the proportion of
the national income absorbed by taxes, has made
the Citizens of our republic inquire more than ever,
Who pays these taxes? The question of who bears
the burden is not simply a matter of who pays taxes
in the first instance, but even more, it is concerned
with who bears them in the end. It thus becomes
of prime importance that the economic forces de-
termining what economists call shifting, or the
passing on to others of the tax burden, be under-
stood.
Some people assume that no taxes are shifted,
or talk as if they believed this, when they complain
of their tax bills. On the other hand, the opposite
and equally erroneous assumption is frequently
made that all taxes are shifted. A specific form
which this second fallacy takes is that the rich can-
not be made to bear taxes, because they will always
shift the burden to others-chiefly to laborers or
consumers. In the last congressional campaign a
United States Senator speaking in a middle western
city made a statement which embodies this widely
held view. He said, in effect, that it does no good
to levy taxes upon the rich, for they merely add
these taxes into the prices of what they sell, and
the great body of the poor and middle class citizens,
because they are consumers, have to pay the taxes
indirectly. The Senator's remark was made in
criticism of the Roosevelt administration's policy
of collecting a large part of the cost of unemploy-
ment relief, as well as of other New Deal expenses,
from those who are more than well to do-that is,
from the rich and near rich.
The theory of taxation implied in the Senator's
statement is widely held, but like many other widely

held beliefs, is only half true. It might be called a
pessimistic theory of taxation-pessimistic from the
standpoint of the great masses of the people-for
it holds that no matter where taxes are levied in
the first place, ultimately the consumer pays them,
and that means for the most part the poor and
middle classes. This belief ignores.the rules of the
shifting of taxes, and therein lies its fallacy.
When economists speak of the shifting of taxes,
they mean the passing of the burden of a tax from
one person to another. If a tax of two cents a
gallon is levied on the gasoline produced by
refineries, it is generally expected that the tax
will be added by the. refiner to his selling price,
and ultimately will be paid by the automobile
owner when he purchases gasoline. The tax,
though imposed initially upon the refiner or im-
porter, is said to be shifted to the ultimate con-
sumer of gasoline, the auto owner.    Another
example: The federal government imposes a tax of
six cents a package upon cigarettes. This tax is
levied upon the manufacturer, and he pays the
money to the government. But in turn the manu-
facturer ordinarily is able to add this tax into the
selling price of the cigarettes, and the smoker pays
that much more for a package than if there were
no tax. In other words, the manufacturer in this
case is able to shift the tax. But suppose that the
gasoline refiner or the tobacco manufacturer were
unable to add the tax into his selling price. In such
a case the tax is said not to be shifted.
It is obvious that the question of the shifting of
taxes is of the greatest, importance. On whom the
burden rests finally is more important than from
whom the tax is collected. Too often legislators
overlook this fact, carelessly imposing taxes with-
out inquiring whether they will be shifted, so that
an entirely different set of people may be called
upon to pay them than the ones who make the
first money payment to the government.
Some taxes, then, are shifted, and others are not.
What are the economic principles determining
whether in a given case shifting will take place?
The principles are complex and the exceptions
many, but the fundamentals may be stated briefly.
In the first place, whether a tax is shifted is not a
question of the desire of the one taxed to be rid
of the burden. That desire can be assumed; when
one can shift a tax, he will. The real question is
not whether the fact that the government has levied
a tax on me makes me want to pass the burden on
to some one else; the real question is whether the
imposing of such a tax gives me the power to raise
the price of what I sell, where I did not have that
power before. If it does give me such power, then
the tax is a shiftable one. Whether or not a tax
can be shifted is therefore not a matter of desire
but of economic laws.
There are various ways in which the subject of
shifting may be approached, but perhaps the simplest
is from the standpoint of the effect of taxation upon
demand and supply. Prices-by this is meant all
kinds of prices, including not only commodity
prices, but rent, interest, and wages-result from
the interaction of demand and supply. That is, a

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most