About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

19 Stan. Tech. L. Rev. 1 (2015-2016)
Bargaining Power and Patent Damages

handle is hein.journals/stantlr19 and id is 9 raw text is: 












BARGAINING POWER AND PATENT DAMAGES


                              J.  Gregory Sidak

                     CITE  AS: 19 STAN.  TECH.   L. REV.  1 (2015)

                                      ABSTRACT

       In patent-infringement litigation, if no established royalty for the patent in suit has
  emerged from multiple market transactions at a readily observable price, then thefinder of
  fact needs to infer a reasonable royalty from the many factors identified in the Georgia-
  Pacific framework. The well-recognized problem with the Georgia-Pacific framework  is
  that it poses many potentially relevant questions but does not say how the finder of fact
  should weight the answers. The case law offers no algorithm or decision tree for the finder of
  fact to follow. Courts find expert testimony inadmissible if it does not apply intellectually
  rigorous economic methods and principles to the facts and data of the case to produce results
  that are replicable and falsifiable. With modest effort, and without repudiating existing
  precedent, the courts can make   the Georgia-Pacific framework   far  more  coherent,
  predictable, and intellectually rigorous. From an economic perspective, that framework
  ultimately leads the finder offactfirst, to determine the gains from trade-which economists
  call surplus-arising from a hypothetical, voluntary negotiation between a willing licensor
  and a willing licensee just before the moment offirst infringement and, second, to divide that
  surplus between the licensor and licensee according to their relative bargaining power. For
  brevity and clarity, I call these two culminating steps the surplus-division principle. This
  principle is more reliable than purporting to set a reasonable royalty on the basis of a
  mathematical theory (such as the Nash bargaining solution) that is too abstract tofit the facts
  and data of the case. It is also more reliable than an expert's idiosyncratic and nonfalsifiable
  claim to have balanced the totality of the circumstances in light of his professional experience.
  In contrast to both a theoretical black box and an expert's ipse dixit, the surplus-division
  principle uses elementary principles of microeconomics to give coherence to the Georgia-
  Pacific factors that courts have already defined and applied. The result enables thefinder of
  fact to determine a licensor's minimum willingness to accept and a licensee's maximum
  willingness to pay for the patented technology, and thereby to define the bargaining range
  for a hypothetical negotiation. This method is robust across different factual scenarios and
  multiple defendants.


1


              Chairman,     Criterion   Economics,     L.L.C.,   Washington,     D.C.    Email:
jgsidak@criterioneconomics.com.   For their helpful comments,  I thank two anonymous   referees
selected by the Stanford Technology  Law  Review pursuant  to its peer-review procedures.  The
views expressed  here are solely my own. 6 2015 J. Gregory Sidak. All rights reserved.

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most