About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

26 Antitrust 73 (2011-2012)
No Poaching Allowed: Antitrust Issues in Labor Markets

handle is hein.journals/antitruma26 and id is 277 raw text is: No Poaching Allowed:
Antitrust Issues in
Labor Markets
BY MICHAEL LINDSAY AND KATHERINE SANTON
most important asset, but unlike other assets,
EMPLOYEES CAN BE A COMPANY'S
employees can walk. When an employee walks out
the door, the employee takes with him the human
capital that results from the joint investment of
the employee (through his time and effort) and the employ-
er (through its formal and informal training programs-
and through the compensation paid to the employee). The
employee might also take business relationships and confi-
dential information. With employee mobility at an all-time
high,' employers might ask how far they can go by agreeing
among themselves to limit the kinds of competition they
will engage in for employment services.
The (unsurprising) answer is not very far. In 2009, the
U.S. Department of Justice investigated allegations of such
agreements among a number of high-tech companies that
restricted their ability to hire each other's employees.2 The
investigation resulted in civil complaints against a number of
high-tech companies,' followed by settlement agreements -
and a federal class action.5 The popular press certainly saw no
difference between hiring-restriction agreements and the
more familiar (and illegal) practice of price fixing. One head-
line referred to it as Tech-Recruiting Collusion,6 and many
others referred to the underlying agreements as anti-poach-
ing.7 Perhaps poaching was already used to describe com-
petition for employees in the high-tech world, but if not, it
came to have that meaning.' The resulting DOJ case, along
with a follow-on federal class action have highlighted the
antitrust aspects of employer competition for employees. So
what are the antitrust guides that employers should follow in
the non-unionized economy?0
Traditional Post-Employment Covenants
Employers traditionally have used both incentives and dis-
incentives to keep valued employees from leaving. Incen-
tives include compensation (salary, bonuses, benefits pack-

ages, and employee-specific perks) and working conditions.
Disincentives include post-employment conditions in an
employment agreement that make leaving relatively less
attractive. For example, an employment agreement might
include a non-compete covenant (employee agrees not to
pursue a similar profession or trade in competition against the
employer within a stated geography for a specified time), a
customer non-solicitation covenant (employee agrees not to
solicit employer's customers, but is otherwise free to compete,
and is free to make unsolicited sales to employer's customers),
a co-employee non-solicitation covenant (employee agrees
not to solicit former co-employees to leave the company), and
confidentiality agreements (employee agrees not to take, use,
or disclose employer's confidential information).
Each of these disincentives is an agreement between the
employer and employee, or in antitrust-speak, between the
buyer and seller. As vertical agreements, these employment
covenants are unlikely to have any antitrust implications.'0
Employment agreements, however, are not a complete or
perfect solution to the problem of protecting an investment
in human capital. State law regulates the enforceability of
post-employment restrictive covenants, and some states
(notably California) severely limit the enforceability of non-
compete and non-solicitation agreements. Especially in a state
that limits enforceability of vertical agreements (that is, of
post-employment covenants with the employee), employers
might look to other means to protect their interests.
No-Switching Agreements Between Competitors
An employer will be particularly concerned if its employee
joins or forms a competitor of the employer-that is,
switches to a competing employer. After all, that is where
the employee's use of knowledge and relationships can hurt
the former employer most. Consequently, an employer might
be tempted to reach an agreement with its competitors not
to hire each other's employees. After all, the employer thinks,
this reaches the same result as a perfectly lawful (in most
states) noncompete agreement with the employee, and it
avoids the messy and fast-paced lawsuit for a temporary
restraining order or preliminary injunction for breach of
employment covenants. And doesn't Section 6 of the Clayton
Act make clear that antitrust laws do not apply to markets for
human labor?
Agreements Between Competitors. Some employers
have tried this approach-and failed. Section 6 clearly does
not provide an antitrust exemption for a buyer cartel for
labor services. For example, in Nichols v. Spencer International
Press, Inc.,'12 two competitors in the sale of encyclopedias and
other reference books had a no switching agreement.
According to the complaint, under their agreement, these
competing firms refused to permit employees or other sales
personnel to go to work for competitors ... and .. . refused
to hire employees and sales personnel with any other defen-
dant or of any other competitor . . . . I' The court rejected
the argument that Section 6 immunized this agreement,

SUMMER  2012  -  73

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most