About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

7 Econ. Comm. Newsl. 17 (2007)
The RPM Controvery: Dr. Miles, Leegin, and beyond

handle is hein.journals/ecoconw7 and id is 41 raw text is: Economics Committee Newsletter

The RPM Controversy: Dr.
Miles, Leegin, and Beyond
Barak Y. Orbach
The University of Arizona, James E. Rogers College
of Law
and Sivan R. Korn
Lewis and Roca, LLP
Introduction
George Bernard Shaw enjoyed telling the
story of Count Leo Tolstoy to illustrate his
argument that the public does not appreciate
what it does not pay for. According to the
story, Tolstoy put into the public domain the
copyrights to his works as a gesture to
mankind, unintentionally causing an
immediate decline in the sales of his books.1
This story captures a common market
phenomenon: the demand for certain goods
increases with price up to a certain point.2
Examples of goods for which demand
curves do not slope downward are
abundant.3 High-end fashion manufacturers
often adjust prices upward to maintain the
luxury status of their brands. For consumers
of fashion houses like Louis Vuitton,
Burberry, or Miu Miu, high price is part of
the product's allure. It confers exclusivity
and prestige.4 In 2002, Tiffany began
aggressively raising prices of its profitable
silver jewelry lines in order to preserve its
image as a high-end, luxury jewelry maker.
Tiffany's executives were concerned that the
popularity of its inexpensive lines of silver
jewelry among middle-class shoppers would
alienate its lucrative clientele of wealthy
luxury consumers.5 Wine is another
example of a product which demand climbs
with its price, up to a certain point.
Similarly, some colleges have discovered
that they were losing applicants when the
tuition was low and attracting more qualified
applicants when tuition is high.6

Many manufacturers use high prices to
acquire and maintain a luxury image,
utilizing various business schemes to
preserve the high level of their prices and
prevent the appearance that their products
can be purchased at bargain prices. One of
the simplest schemes to accomplish this goal
is resale price maintenance (RPM). In
June 2007, the Supreme Court, divided 5-4,
handed down its decision in Leegin,7
reversing the almost century old per se
prohibition against RPM established by Dr.
Miles (1911).8
The economic logic of the per se illegality
of RPM has always been controversial,
although the number of Dr. Miles supporters
has dramatically declined over time. In
Leegin, the Supreme Court did not declare
RPM to be per se legal;9 rather, it held that
courts should examine RPM practices under
the rule of reason. In this article, we review
the RPM controversy, presenting the
traditional arguments for and against per se
illegality of RPM and emphasizing one of
the most straightforward motivations for
RPM - high prices as a product feature. The
latter reason has played a background role in
many RPM cases, including Leegin,
although courts rarely address it directly.
The myriad of competitive and
anticompetitive effects of RPM suggest that
per se illegality is indeed an undesirable
standard.
The Underlying Questions
The RPM controversy involves one
substantive question and two administrative
questions. The substantive question is
whether RPM is always or almost always
anticompetitive and, therefore, should be
illegal per se.10 The administrative
questions concern the impact of reversing a
per se rule on business certainty and courts'
ability to evaluate the competitive effects of
RPM. Dissenting in Leegin, Justice Breyer

i ulne7Nme                             al20

Volume 7, Number 2

Fall 2007

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most