About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

42 Stan. L. Rev. 927 (1989-1990)
Problematic Relations: Franchising the Law of Incomplete Contracts

handle is hein.journals/stflr42 and id is 943 raw text is: Problematic Relations: Franchising and
the Law of Incomplete Contracts
Gillian K. Hadfield*
Commitments to take or refrain from taking certain actions are in-
dispensable elements in most forms of interaction and exchange. Even
the purest form of spot-market transaction rests on commitments: the
commitment of the state to value a piece of paper in future exchanges,
and the commitment of the individual not to steal back what has been
sold. As transactions spread out over time and become more complex,
however, more is needed to ground the exchange than the mere stabil-
ity of currency and property: The solidity of contract is also required.
In the case of the complete contract, which specifies in a manner
immediately verifiable by a third party precisely what performances are
required for all possible future conditions, classical notions of contract
enforcement serve well to secure the commitment supporting the trans-
action. In this case, courts stand ready to examine the contract and,
going no further than the balance reached in this private ordering, hold
the parties to their commitments.'
In reality, few contracts can be complete. Accordingly, classical
contract law has always provided for the accidental failure of complete-
ness resulting from linguistic ambiguity, or from the absence of provi-
sions specifying the performances required under certain, perhaps
unanticipated, conditions. More recently, however, contract scholars
have recognized that the failure of completeness is not always a mere
stumble on the classical path.2 Often, contracts are necessarily and in-
tentionally incomplete because mutual desires for flexible, but
* Acting Professor, University of California at Berkeley (Boalt Hall). Doctoral Candi-
date (Economics), Stanford University. J.D., Stanford Law School, 1988. The author received
the 1988 Richard S. Goldsmith Award at Stanford Law School for this article; an earlier ver-
sion appeared in the Stanford Center on Conflict and Negotiation Working Paper Series.
This work was completed while I was a New Directions Mellon Fellow at Stanford University.
I am grateful to the Mellon Foundation and theJohn M. Olin Program in Law and Economics
at Stanford Law School for support. I thank Bob Gordon, Peter Menell, Mitch Polinsky, Todd
Rakoff, Roberta Romano,Judge Stephen Williams and Ralph A. Winter for useful discussions,
and participants in the faculty workshops at Berkeley, Chicago, Columbia, Harvard, Michigan,
New York University, Stanford, and Yale law schools for comments and criticism.
1. The courts may also face a commitment problem in carrying out the sanctions that
contract law requires. Courts may be tempted to relieve the parties of their cc ante obligations.
I will not deal directly here with this aspect of commitment.
2. See, e.g., Oliver E. Williamson, Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual
Relations, 22J.L. & EcON. 233, 235-38 (1979).

927

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most