About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

1 1 (July 21, 2022)

handle is hein.crs/goveihy0001 and id is 1 raw text is: Congressional Research Service
Informing the Iegitive debate since 1914

Updated July 21, 2022

Antitrust Law: An Introduction
Recent years have witnessed a resurgence of both popular
and political interest in antitrust. This renewed attention has
produced a flurry of legislative activity, with several
Members of Congress introducing proposals to reform
various elements of competition law. This In Focus
provides an overview of antitrust doctrine and selected
antitrust legislation pending before Congress.
The Goats of Antitrust
The antitrust laws are designed to protect economic
competition. At that level of generality, there is little
controversy. However, there is profound disagreement
about antitrust's more specific goals. Safeguarding
competition can mean a variety of things, and disputes
about the appropriate targets of antitrust policy have
persisted since its inception.
Economists tend to approach this issue with similar
discussions of the effects of market power-the ability of a
firm to profitably charge prices above levels that would
prevail in a competitive market. Economic theory identifies
two relevant effects. First, market power can produce
allocative inefficiency: when prices exceed competitive
levels, some consumers who would have purchased a
product at the competitive price choose to forgo it or
substitute less desired alternatives. Thus, market power can
lead to suboptimal allocations of scarce resources. Second,
market power can result in wealth transfers: consumers
who buy a product at an uncompetitive price are poorer
than they would be in a competitive market, while the seller
is richer.
Today, antitrust is principally concerned with preventing
anticompetitive conduct that enables firms to exercise
market power. However, the distinct effects of market
power highlight a fissure in the debate over antitrust's more
foundational goals. In a narrow subset of cases, efficiency
and consumer welfare may pull in opposite directions. For
example, some mergers may lower production costs, but
also increase market power. Some commentators-
advocates of a total welfare standard-maintain that
antitrust should permit such transactions as long as the
gains in productive efficiency outweigh the losses in
allocative efficiency and consumer welfare. By contrast,
defenders of the consumer welfare standard advocate
blocking such deals when they are likely to effectuate a
wealth transfer from consumers to producers. Although the
competition laws of some countries embrace the
total-welfare standard, U.S. antitrust doctrine prioritizes
consumer welfare and does not typically permit producer
gains to offset downstream harms.
While the consumer-welfare standard thus plays a central
role in contemporary U.S. antitrust, some have suggested

that it is both descriptively and normatively incomplete.
One point of contention involves anticompetitive conduct
by buyers, which most directly harms sellers rather than end
consumers. Whether-and how-such harms are relevant
under the consumer-welfare standard is a complicated
question. In some cases, reductions in buy-side competition
do harm consumers. For example, a merger that gives a
firm the ability to depress input prices by purchasing less
may harm consumers by leading to lower output. In other
buy-side cases, however, injuries may be limited to sellers.
For example, a merger might increase a firm's bargaining
leverage with suppliers without giving it incentives to
purchase fewer inputs. In that case, the main effect of
diminished competition may be a wealth transfer from
sellers to the powerful buyer, without any effects on final
output. Powerful buyers may even benefit consumers by
passing along some of their cost savings. Some
commentators have appealed to these fact patterns to argue
that trading partner welfare or safeguarding the
competitive process represent more descriptively accurate
and normatively desirable benchmarks for antitrust policy
than consumer welfare. The possible tension between these
goals and the consumer-welfare standard may become
increasingly salient as antitrust enforcers take a greater
interest in labor markets, where workers rather than
consumers are the most direct victims of anticompetitive
conduct.
The above discussion does not exhaust the possible ends
that antitrust can serve. There is a long-standing debate over
whether antitrust should promote noneconomic objectives
like personal liberty, protecting small entrepreneurs, or
preserving the integrity of the political process. Although
there has recently been a resurgence of interest in such
goals among some antitrust commentators, those
considerations have not played an explicit role in the
development of antitrust decision rules for several decades.
The Key Statutes
The persistence of disputes over antitrust's goals may be
partially attributable to the sparseness of the key federal
antitrust statutes. The three core provisions-Sections 1 and
2 of the Sherman Act and Section 7 of the Clayton Act-
are succinct and vague, effectively granting the federal
courts common law authority to fashion competition policy
based on prevailing economic theories.
Section 1 of the Sherman Act: Restraints of Trade
Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits contracts in
restraint of trade. Under Section 1 doctrine, a few types of
agreements are per se illegal because they almost always
harm competition. The per se category now encompasses
horizontal price fixing, horizontal market allocation, and
some horizontal boycotts. (In antitrust parlance, agreements

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most