About | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline Law Journal Library | HeinOnline

15 J.L. & Econ. 143 (1972)
Durability and Monopoly

handle is hein.journals/jlecono15 and id is 147 raw text is: DURABILITY AND MONOPOLY
R. H. COASE
University of Chicago Law School
ASSUME that a supplier owns the total stock of a completely durable good.
At what price will he sell it? To take a concrete example, assume that one
person owns all the land in the United States and, to simplify the analysis,
that all land is of uniform quality. Assume also that the landowner is not
able to work the land himself, that ownership of land yields no utility and
that there are no costs involved in disposing of the land. If there were a large
number of landowners and the price were competitively determined, the price
would be that at which the amount demanded was equal to the amount of land
in the United States. If we imagine this fixed supply of land to be various
amounts either greater or smaller, and then discover what the competitively
determined price would be, we can trace out the demand schedule for American
land. Assume that this demand schedule is DD and that from this a marginal
revenue schedule, MR, has been derived. Both schedules are shown in Figure
I. Let the total amount of land in existence be OQ. Then, if the price were
competitively determined, the price would be OB (see Figure I).
We now have to determine the price which the monopolistic landowner
would charge for a unit of land in the assumed conditions. The diagram would
seem to suggest (and has, I believe, suggested to some) that such a monopolis-
tic landowner would charge the price OA, would sell the quantity of land OM,
thus maximising his receipts, and would hold off the market the quantity of
land, MQ. But suppose that he did this. MQ land and money equal to OA X
OM would be in the possession of the original landowner while OM land
would be owned by others. In these circumstances, why should the original
landowner continue to hold MQ off the market? The original landowner could
obviously improve his position by selling more land since he could by this
means acquire more money. It is true that this would reduce the value of the
land OM owned by those who had previously bought land from him-but the
loss would fall on them, not on him. If the same assumption about his be-
haviour was made as before, he would then sell part of MQ. But this is not
the end of the story, since some of MQ would still remain unsold. The process
would continue as long as the original landowner retained any land, that is,
until OQ had been sold. And if there were no costs of disposing of the land, the
whole process would take place in the twinkling of an eye.

What Is HeinOnline?

HeinOnline is a subscription-based resource containing thousands of academic and legal journals from inception; complete coverage of government documents such as U.S. Statutes at Large, U.S. Code, Federal Register, Code of Federal Regulations, U.S. Reports, and much more. Documents are image-based, fully searchable PDFs with the authority of print combined with the accessibility of a user-friendly and powerful database. For more information, request a quote or trial for your organization below.



Short-term subscription options include 24 hours, 48 hours, or 1 week to HeinOnline.

Contact us for annual subscription options:

Already a HeinOnline Subscriber?

profiles profiles most